Untitled

An Economic Examination of Collateralization in Different Financial Markets

Tim Xiao

ABSTRACT

This paper attempts to assess the economic significance and implications of collateralization in different financial markets, which is essentially a matter of theoretical justification and empirical verification. We present a comprehensive theoretical framework that allows for collateralization adhering to bankruptcy laws. As such, the model can back out differences in asset prices due to collateralized counterparty risk. This framework is very useful for pricing outstanding defaultable financial contracts. By using a unique data set, we are able to achieve a clean decomposition of prices into their credit risk factors. We find empirical evidence that counterparty risk is not overly important in credit-related spreads. Only the joint effects of collateralization and credit risk can sufficiently explain unsecured credit costs. This finding suggests that failure to properly account for collateralization may result in significant mispricing of financial contracts. We also analyze the difference between cleared and OTC markets.

Key words: unilateral/bilateral collateralization, partial/full/over collateralization, asset pricing, plumbing of the financial system, swap premium spread, OTC/cleared/listed financial markets.

JEL Classification: E44, G21, G12, G24, G32, G33, G18, G28

  1. Introduction

Collateralization is an essential element in the so-called plumbing of the financial system that is the Achilles' heel of global financial markets. It allows financial institutions to reduce economic capital and credit risk, free up lines of credit, and expand the range of counterparties. All of these factors contribute to the growth of financial markets. The benefits are broadly acknowledged and affect dealers and end users, as well as the financial system generally.

The reason collateralization of financial derivatives and repos has become one of the most important and widespread credit risk mitigation techniques is that the Bankruptcy Code contains a series of “safe harbor” provisions to exempt these contracts from the “automatic stay”. The automatic stay prohibits the creditors from undertaking any act that threatens the debtor’s asset, while the safe harbor, a luxury, permits the creditors to terminate derivative and repo contracts with the debtor in bankruptcy and to seize the underlying collateral. This paper focuses on safe harbor contracts (e.g., derivatives and repos), but many of the points made are equally applicable to automatic stay contracts.

Financial derivatives can be categorized into three types. The first category is over-the-counter (OTC) derivatives, which are customized bilateral agreements. The second group is cleared derivatives, which are negotiated bilaterally but booked with a clearinghouse. Finally, the third type is exchange-traded/listed derivatives, which are executed over an exchange. The differences between the three types are described in detail on the International Swap Dealers Association (ISDA) website (see ISDA (2013)).

Under the new regulations (e.g., Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform Act), certain ‘eligible’ OTC derivatives must be cleared with central counterparties (CCPs) (see Heller and Vause (2012), Pirrong (2011), etc.). Hull (2011) further recommends mandatory CCP clearing of all OTC derivatives. Meanwhile, Duffie and Zhu (2011) suggest a move toward the joint clearing of interest rate swaps and credit default swaps (CDS) in the same clearinghouse.

The posting of collateral is regulated by the Credit Support Annex (CSA). The CSA was originally designed for OTC derivatives, but more recently has been updated for cleared/listed derivatives. For this reason people in the financial industry often refer to collateralized contracts as CSA contracts and non-collateralized contracts as non-CSA contracts.

There are three types of collateralization: full, partial or over. Full-collateralization is a process where the posting of collateral is equal to the current mark-to-market (MTM) value. Partial/under-collateralization is a process where the posting of collateral is less than the current MTM value. Over-collateralization is a process where the posting of collateral is greater than the current MTM value.

From the perspective of collateral obligations, collateral arrangements can be unilateral or bilateral. In a unilateral arrangement, only one predefined counterparty has the right to call for collateral. Unilateral agreements are generally used when the other counterparty is much less creditworthy. In a bilateral arrangement, on the other hand, both counterparties have the right to call for collateral.

Upon default and early termination, the values due under the ISDA Master Agreement are determined. These amounts are then netted and a single net payment is made. All of the collateral on hand would be available to satisfy this total amount, up to the full value of that collateral. In other words, the collateral to be posted is calculated on the basis of the aggregated value of the portfolio, but not on the basis of any individual transaction.

The use of collateral in financial markets has increased sharply over the past decade, yet analytical and empirical research on collateralization is relatively sparse. The effect of collateralization on financial contracts is an understudied area. Collateral management is often carried out in an ad-hoc manner, without reference to an analytical framework. Comparatively little research has been done to analytically and empirically assess the economic significance and implications of collateralization. Such a quantitative and empirical analysis is the primary contribution of this paper.

Due to the complexity of quantifying collateralization, previous studies seem to turn away from direct and detailed modeling of collateralization (see Fuijii and Takahahsi (2012)). For example, Johannes and Sundaresan (2007), and Fuijii and Takahahsi (2012) characterize collateralization via a cost-of-collateral instantaneous rate (or stochastic dividend or convenience yield). Piterbarg (2010) regards collateral as a regular asset in a portfolio and uses the replication approach to price collateralized contracts. All of the previous works focus on full-collateralization only.

We obtain the CSA data from two investment banks. The data show that only 8.92% of CSA counterparties are subject to unilateral collateralization, while the remaining 91.08% are bilaterally collateralized. The data also reveal that all contracts in OTC markets are partially collateralized due to the mechanics of CSAs, which allow for the existence of limited unsecured exposures and set minimum transfer amounts (MTAs), whereas all contracts in cleared/listed markets are over-collateralized as all CCPs/Exchanges require initial margins. Therefore, full-collateralization does not exist in the real world[1]. The reason for the popularity of full-collateralization is its mathematical simplicity and tractability.

This article makes a theoretical and empirical contribution to the study of collateralization by addressing several essential questions concerning the posting of collateral. First, how does collateralization affect expected asset prices? To answer this question, we develop a comprehensive analytical framework for pricing financial contracts under different (partial/full/over and unilateral /bilateral) collateral arrangements in different (OTC/cleared/listed) markets.

In contrast to other collateralization models in current literature, we characterize a collateral process directly based on the fundamental principal and legal structure of the CSA agreement. A model is devised that allows for collateralization adhering to bankruptcy laws. As such, the model can back out differences in prices due to counterparty risk. This framework is very useful for valuing off-the-run or outstanding financial contracts subject to credit risk and collateralization, where the price quotes are not available. Given this model, we are able to explain credit-related spreads and provide an important tool for credit value adjustment (CVA).

Our theoretical analysis shows that collateralization can always improve recovery and reduce credit risk. If a contract is over-collateralized (e.g., a repo or cleared contract), its value is equal to the risk-free value. If a contract is partially collateralized (e.g., an OTC derivatives), its CSA value is less than the risk-free value but greater than the non-CSA risky value.

Second, how can the model be empirically verified? To achieve the verification goal, this paper empirically measures the effect of collateralization on pricing and compares it with model-implied prices. This calls for data on financial contracts that have different collateral arrangements but are similar otherwise. We use a unique interest rate swap contract data set from an investment bank for the empirical study, as interest rate swaps collectively account for around two-thirds of both the notional and market value of all outstanding derivatives.

ISDA mid-market swap rates quoted in the market are based on hypothetical counterparties of AA-rated quality or better. Dealers use this market rate as a reference when quoting an actual swap rate to a client and make adjustments based on many factors, such as credit risk, liquidity risk, funding cost, operational cost and expected profit, etc. Unlike most other studies, this study mainly concentrates the analysis on swap adjustments/premia related to credit risk and collateralization, which are to be made to the mid-market swap rates for real counterparties.

Prior research has primarily focused on the generic mid-market swap rates and results appear puzzling. Sorensen and Bollier (1994) believe that swap spreads (i.e., the difference between swap rates and par yields on similar maturity Treasuries) are partially determined by counterparty default risk. Whereas Duffie and Huang (1996), Hentschel and Smith (1997), Minton (1997) and Grinblatt (2001) find weak or no evidence of the impact of counterparty credit risk on swap spreads. Collin-Dufresne and Solnik (2001) and He (2001) further argue that many credit enhancement devices, e.g., collateralization, have essentially rendered swap contracts risk-free. Meanwhile, Duffie and Singleton (1997), and Liu, Longstaff and Mandell (2006) conclude that both credit and liquidity risks have an impact on swap spreads. Moreover, Feldhütter and Lando (2008) find that the liquidity factor is the largest component of swap spreads. It seems that there is no clear-cut answer yet regarding the relative contribution of the liquidity and credit factors. Maybe, the recently revealed LIBOR scandal can partially explain these conflicting findings.

Unlike the generic mid-market swap rates, swap premia are determined in a competitive market according to the basic principles of supply and demand. A client who wants to enter a swap contract first contacts a number of swap dealers and asks for a swap rate. After comparing all quotations, the client chooses the most competitive rate. A swap premium is supposed to cover operational, liquidity, funding, and credit costs as well as a profit margin. If the premium is too low, the dealer may lose money. If the premium is too high, the dealer may lose the competitive advantage.

Unfortunately, we do not know the detailed allocation of a swap premium, i.e., what percentage of the adjustment is charged for each factor. Thus, a direct empirical verification is impossible.

To circumvent this difficulty, this article uses an indirect process to verify the model empirically. We define a swap premium spread as the difference between the swap premia of two collateralized swap contracts that have exactly the same terms and conditions but are traded with different counterparties under different collateral agreements. We reasonably believe that if two contracts are identical except counterparties, the premium spread should reflect the difference between two counterparties’ unsecured credit risks only, as all other risks and costs are identical.

Empirically, we find quite a number of CSA swap pairs in the data, where the two contracts in each pair have different counterparties but are otherwise the same. The test results demonstrate that the model-implied swap premium spreads are very close to the market swap premium spreads, indicating that the model is quite accurate.

Finally, how does collateralization impact pricing in different markets? Our proprietary data reveal that cleared swaps have dramatically increased since 2011, reflecting the financial institutions’ compliance to regulatory requirements. We find evidence that the economical determination of swap rates in cleared markets is the same as that in OTC markets, as all clearinghouses claim that cleared derivatives would replicate OTC derivatives, and promise that transactions through the clearinghouses would be economically equivalent to similar transactions handled in OTC markets.

Although the practice recommended by CCPs is popular in the market, in which derivatives are continuously negotiated over-the-counter as usual but cleared and settled through clearinghouses, some market participants cast doubt on CCPs’ economic equivalence claim. They find that cleared contracts have actually significant differences when compared with OTC trades. Some firms even file legal action against the clearinghouses, and accuse them of fraudulently inducing the firms to enter into cleared derivatives on the premise the contracts would be economically equivalent to OTC contracts (see Pengelly (2011)).

In fact, our study shows that there are many differences between cleared markets and OTC markets. After much discussion, we come to the conclusion that cleared derivatives are not economically equivalent to their OTC counterparts. These discussions may be of interest to regulators, academics and practitioners.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 discusses unilateral collateralization. Section 3 elaborates bilateral collateralization. Section 4 presents empirical evidence. The conclusions and discussion are provided in Section 5. All proofs and some detailed derivations are contained in the appendices.

  1. Unilateral Collateralization

A unilateral collateral arrangement is sometimes used when a higher-rated counterparty deals with a lower-rated counterparty, in which only one party, normally the lower-rated one, is required to deliver collateral to guarantee performance under the agreement. Typical examples of unilaterally collateralized contracts include: repos, cleared/listed derivatives, sovereign derivatives (see AFME-ICMA-ISDA (2011)), and some OTC derivatives[2].

It is well-known that the survival probability from time t to s in this framework is defined by

The default probability for the period (t, s) in this framework is given by

In order to assess the impact of collateralization on pricing, we study valuation with and without collateralization respectively.

    1. Valuation without collateralization

where

Similarly, we have

In theory, a default may happen at any time, i.e., a risky contract is continuously defaultable. This Continuous Time Risky Valuation Model is accurate but sometimes complex and expensive. For simplicity, people sometimes prefer the Discrete Time Risky Valuation Model that assumes that a default may only happen at some discrete times. A natural selection is to assume that a default may occur only on the payment dates. Fortunately, the level of accuracy for this discrete approximation is well inside the typical bid-ask spread for most applications (see O’Kane and Turnbull (2003)). From now on, we will focus on the discrete setting only, but many of the points we make are equally applicable to the continuous setting.

If we assume that a default may occur only on the payment date, the non-CSA value of the instrument in the discrete-time setting is given by

The difference between the risk-free value and the risky value is known as the credit value adjustment (CVA). CVA is required by regulators, such as, International Accounting Standard Board (IASB) and Basel committee. The CVA reflects the market value of counterparty risk or the cost of protection required to hedge counterparty risk and is given by

    1. Valuation with collateralization

The posting of collateral is regulated by the CSA that specifies a variety of terms including the threshold, the independent amount, and the minimum transfer amount (MTA), etc. The threshold is the unsecured credit exposure that a party is willing to bear. The MTA is used to avoid the workload associated with a frequent transfer of insignificant amounts of collateral. The independent amount plays the same role as the initial margin (or haircut).

We define effective collateral threshold as the threshold plus the MTA. The collateral is called as soon as the mark-to-market (MTM) value rises above the effective threshold. A positive effective threshold corresponds to partial/under-collateralization where the posting of collateral is less than the MTM value. A negative effective threshold represents over-collateralization where the posting of collateral is greater than the MTM value. A zero-value effective threshold equates with full-collateralization where the posting of collateral is equal to the MTM value.

Suppose that there is a unilateral CSA agreement between parties A and B in which only party B is required to deliver collateral when the mark-to-market (MTM) value arises over the collateral threshold H.

The choice of modeling assumptions for collateralization should be based on the legal structure of collateral agreements. According to the Bankruptcy Law, if the collateral value is greater than the default claim, creditors can only have a claim on the collateral up to the full amount of their default demand. Any excess collateral is returned to the estate of the failed institution for the payment of unsecured creditors. If the demand for default payment exceeds the collateral value, the balance of the demand will be treated as an unsecured claim and subject to its pro rate distribution under the Bankruptcy Code’s priority scheme (see Garlson (1992), Routh and Douglas (2005), and Edwards and Morrison (2005)). The default payment under a collateral agreement, therefore, can be mathematically expressed as

or

Let us consider repo/cleared/listed markets first. Contracts in these markets are always over collateralized, as the parties with collateral obligation are required to deposit initial margins and are also charged variation margins in response to changes in the market values. The total collateral (initial margin plus variation margin) posted at time t is given by

Equation (13) tells us that the CSA value of an over-collateralized contract is equal to the risk-free value. This result is consistent with the market practice in which market participants commonly assume that repos and cleared contracts are virtually free of default risk because of the implicit guarantee of the contracts provided by the clearinghouse and backup collateral.

It is worth keeping in mind that clearing does not eliminate any risk. It has no effect on the counterparty’s default probability and does not improve the counterparty’s credit rating. Instead, it uses some mitigation tools, e.g., collateralization, to perfectly hedge the credit risk, making a contract appear to be risk-free.

or

In contrast to repo/cleared markets, collateral posted in OTC markets is a nonlinear function of daily market value changes. In fact, this discontinuous and state-dependent indicator function is the root cause of the complexity of collateralized valuation in OTC markets.

Suppose that default probabilities are uncorrelated with interest rates and payoffs[4]. We have the following proposition after some simple mathematics.

Proposition 1: The unilateral CSA value of the partially collateralized single-payment contract is given by

where

Proof: See the Appendix.

Proposition 2: The unilateral CSA value of the partially collateralized multiple-payment contract is given by

where

Proof: See the Appendix.

  1. Bilateral Collateralization

A bilateral collateral arrangement enables the counterparties to pass collateral between each other to cover the net MTM exposure of the contracts. Under a two-way arrangement, the collateralization obligation is mutual and applicable to both the client and dealer. Bilateral collateralization most likely appears in OTC markets.

For a two-way CSA, each party has an effective collateral threshold and is required to post collateral to the other as exposures arise. The collateral amount at t is given by

or

Proposition 3: The bilateral CSA value of the partially collateralized single-payment contract is given by

where

Proof: See the Appendix.

Table 1. Payoffs of a bilaterally collateralized contract

where

Similar to Proposition 2, the individual payoffs in equation (21) are coupled and cannot be evaluated separately. The process requires a backward induction valuation.

  1. Empirical Results

The objective of this paper is to assess the economic significance and implications of collateralization, which is essentially a matter of theoretical justification and empirical verification. We choose interest rate swaps for our empirical study, as they are the largest component of the global OTC derivative market, collectively accounting for around two-thirds of both the notional and market value of all outstanding derivatives.

Swap rate is the fixed rate that sets the market value of a given swap at initiation to zero. ISDA established ISDAFIX in 1998 in cooperation with Reuters (now Thomson Reuters) and Intercapital Brokers (now ICAP PLC). Each day ISDAFIX establishes average mid-market swap rates at key terms to maturity. These generic benchmark swap rates are based on a rigorously organized daily poll: An ICAP or Reuters representative canvasses a panel of dealers for their par swap rate quotes as of a specified local mid-day time. For any given swap term to maturity, the rate provided by the contributing dealer is the midpoint of where that dealer would itself offer and bid a swap for a certain notional. The mid-market benchmark rate for any given swap tenor is determined as a trimmed mean. Reuters and Bloomberg post the mid-market rates as soon as polling is completed.

In practice, the mid-market swap rates are generally not the actual swap rates transacted with counterparties, but are instead the benchmarks against which the actual swap rates are set. A swap dealer that arranges a contract and provides liquidity to the market involves costs, e.g., hedging cost, credit cost, liquidity cost, operational cost, tax cost, and economic capital cost, etc. Therefore, it is necessary to adjust the mid-market swap rate to cover various costs of transacting and also to provide a profit margin to the dealer that makes the market. As a result, the actual price agreed for the transaction is not zero but a positive amount to the dealer.

Unlike the generic benchmark swap rates, swap premia are determined according to the basic principles of supply and demand. The swap market is highly competitive. In a competitive market, prices are determined by the impersonal forces of demand and supply, but not by manipulations of powerful buyers or sellers. If a premium is set too low, the dealer may lose money. If the premium is set too high, the dealer may lose the competitive advantage.

In contrast to most previous studies that focus on the generic swap rates, this article mainly studies swap adjustments/premia related to credit risk and collateralization. It empirically measures the effect of collateralization on pricing and compares it with model-implied prices.

A swap premium is supposed to cover the expected profit and all the expenses, including the cost of bearing unsecured credit risk. Unfortunately, however, we do not know what percentage of the market swap premium is allocated to the unsecured credit risk, which makes a direct verification impossible.

To circumvent this difficulty, we design an indirect verification process in which we select some CSA swap pairs, where the two contracts in each pair have exactly the same terms and conditions but are traded with different counterparties under different collateral agreements. It is reasonable to believe that the only difference between the two contracts in each pair is the difference in unsecured credit risk between two counterparties, as all other risks and costs are identical. Therefore, by taking credit risk and collateralization into account only, we can compare the model-implied swap premium spreads with the market swap premium spreads for these pairs.

We obtain a unique proprietary data set from an investment bank (FinPricing (2018)). The data set contains swap contract data, counterparty data (including collateral agreements, recovery rates, etc), and market data. The trading dates are from May 6, 2005 to May 11, 2012. The data show that before 2011 the dealer traded interest rate swaps with a large number of counterparties. But sine 2011, the transactions have been concentrated in a few clearinghouses, which reflect financial institutions’ compliance with the regulatory requirements. Consequently, we divide the data into two categories: the OTC data set containing all the transactions traded with regular counterparties and the cleared data set holding all the contracts cleared in CCPs.

Let us examine the OTC data first. We find a total of 1002 swap pairs in the OTC data set, where the two contracts in each pair have the same terms and conditions but are traded with different counterparties under different collateral arrangements. We arbitrarily select one pair shown in Table 2.

Table 2: A pair of 20-year swap contracts

This table displays the terms and conditions of two swap contracts. They have different counterparties but are otherwise the same. We hide the counterparty names according to the security policy of the investment bank while everything else is authentic.

An interest rate curve is the term structure of interest rates, derived from observed market instruments that represent the most liquid and dominant interest rate products for certain time horizons. Normally the curve is divided into three parts. The short end of the term structure is determined using the LIBOR rates. The middle part of the curve is constructed using Eurodollar futures that require convexity adjustments. The far end is derived using mid swap rates. The LIBOR-future-swap curve is presented in Table 3. After bootstrapping the curve, we get the continuously compounded zero rates.

Table 3: USD LIBOR-future-swap curve

This table displays the closing mid prices as of September 15, 2005

As the payoff of an interest rate swap is determined by interest rates, we need to model the evolution of the floating rates. Interest rate models are based on evolving either short rates, instantaneous forward rates, or market forward rates (e.g., the LIBOR Market Model (LMM)). Since both short rates and instantaneous forward rates are not directly observable in the market, the models based on these rates have difficulties in expressing market views and quotes in term of model parameters, and lack agreement with market valuation formulas for basic derivatives. On the other hand, the object modeled under the LMM is market-observable. It is also consistent with the market standard approach for pricing caps/floors using Black’s formula. They are generally considered to have more desirable theoretical calibration properties than short rate or instantaneous forward rate models. Therefore, we choose the LMM lattice proposed by Xiao (2011) for pricing collateralized swaps. We also implement the Hull-White trinomial tree to verify the results and ensure robustness of the valuation. This paper, however, only reports the results produced by the LMM lattice.

According to equation (21), we also need counterparty-related information, such as recovery rates, hazard rates and collateral thresholds. The CDS spreads and recovery rates are given in Table 4. We can compute the hazard rates via a standard calibration process (see J.P. Morgan [2001]).

Table 4: CDS premia and recovery rates

This table displays the closing CDS premia as of September 15, 2005 and recovery rates

Table 5: CSA agreement

This table provides the collateral thresholds and MTAs under the CSA agreements.

The collateral thresholds and MTAs of the CSA agreements are displayed in Table 5. The effective collateral threshold is equal to the threshold plus the MTA.

Given the above information, we are able to compute the collateralized swap rates. We first use the LMM to evolve the interest rates and then determine the associated CSA-adjusted discount factors as well as the cost of bearing unsecured credit risk according to equation (21). Finally, we calculate the collateralized swap rates via backward induction method. The results are given in table 6.

Table 6: Swap rate results

This table presents the model-implied swap rates and premia as well as the dealer-quoted swap rates and premia, where Swap premium (in bps) = Swap rate – Generic swap rate, and Premium spread = Premium of swap 2 – Premium of swap 1.

The 20-year generic mid-market swap rate is 0.048771 shown in Table 3. The swap rates of contracts 1 and 2 are given in Table 2 as 0.049042 and 0.049053. Accordingly, the market swap premia are 2.71 (0.049042 - 0.048771) basis points (bps) and 2.82 bps, respectively. These premia are charged for many expenses, e.g., operational, liquidity, funding, credit, etc., as well as profit margins. Although we do not know what percentage of the premia are allocated to cover the unsecured credit risks, we reasonably believe that the market premium spread, 0.11 bps in Table 6, should reflect the difference between the counterparties’ unsecured credit risks only, as other factors are identical.

By taking credit risk and collateralization into account only, we calculate the model-implied swap rates as 0.048780 and 0.048790 shown in Table 6. Consequently, the implied swap premia are 0.09 bps and 0.19 bps. The results imply that only a small portion of a swap premium is attributed to unsecured credit risk. This is in line with the findings of Duffie and Huang (1996), Duffie and Singleton (1997), and Minton (1997). Table 6 shows that the model-implied swap premium spread is quite close to the dealer-quoted swap premium spread, suggesting that the model is fairly accurate in pricing collateralized financial instruments.

Repeating this exercise for the remaining pairs, we find that the model-implied swap premia fluctuate randomly around the market swap premia. The summary statistics of the market quoted premium spreads, the model-implied premium spreads, and the model-market premium spread differentials are presented in Table 7, where we refer to the differences between the model-implied premium spreads and the market quoted premium spreads as the model-market premium spread differentials. As can be seen from Table 7, the average of the model-market spread differentials is only -0.03 bps, which can be partly attributed to noises. The results indicate prima facie that the model performs quite well. The empirical tests corroborate the theoretical prediction on the impact of collateralization on swap rates.

Table 7: Summary statistics of implied swap premium spreads, market swap premium spreads and model-market swap premium spread differentials

All values are displayed in bps. Model-market premium spread differential = Model-implied premium spread – Market-quoted premium spread.

Next, we examine the effects of credit risk and collateralization, alone or combined, on swap premium spreads. First, we study the marginal effect of credit risk. For each swap pair, we calculate the difference between the CDS spreads of the two counterparties. Presumably, differences in CDS spreads should mainly represent differences in pure credit risk. To determine the strength of the statistical relationship between market swap premium spreads and differences between associated CDS spreads, we present the estimate of the following regression model.

Table 8: Marginal credit risk regression results for the OTC data

This table presents the regression results for the following regression model in the OTC market:

Market swap premium spreads are used as the dependent variable and differences between CDS spreads as the explanatory variable.

According to ISDA Margin Survey (ISDA (2012), 84% of OTC derivatives transactions executed by large derivatives dealers are subject to collateral agreements. Accounting for collateralization has become increasingly important in pricing OTC contracts in financial markets. Since the implied premium spreads generated by our model above take into account both credit risk and collateralization, the statistical relationship between the market premium spreads and the implied premium spreads should refer to the joint effect of counterparty risk and collateralization on market spreads. Thus, we present a regression model where the market swap premium spreads are regressed on the implied swap premium spreads. The regression results are shown in Table 9.

Table 9: Credit risk and collateralization combined regression results for the OTC data

This table presents the regression results for the following regression model in the OTC market:

The market swap premium spreads are used as a dependent variable and the implied swap premium spreads as the explanatory variable.

Finally, we turn to cleared markets. We have found a total of 403 swap pairs in the cleared data set, where the two contracts in each pair have the same terms and conditions. The statistics of market-quoted swap premium spreads for both the OTC data set and the cleared data set are presented in Table 10. It is shown from the table that swap premium spreads in cleared markets behave in the same way as those in OTC markets, i.e., market swap premium spreads in both cleared markets and OTC markets are statistical similar.

We empirically demonstrate that under the new regulatory rules, derivative are continuously negotiated over-the-counter as usual, and then cleared and settled through a clearinghouse. Since clearinghouses claim that cleared derivatives would replicate OTC derivatives and promise that transactions through the clearinghouses would be economically equivalent to similar transactions handled in OTC markets, swap rates in cleared markets are determined in the same way as those in OTC markets.

Table 10: Statistics of market observed swap premium spreads

This table presents descriptive statistics for market swap premium spreads in both OTC and cleared markets. All values are expressed in bps.

Many market participants, however, have cast doubt on the claim of economic equivalence. They find that cleared contracts have actually significant differences when compared with OTC trades. Some firms even file legal action against the clearinghouses, and accuse them of fraudulently inducing the firms to enter into cleared derivatives on the premise the contracts would be economically equivalent to OTC contracts (see Pengelly (2011)).

There are many reasons to question this practice. First, the results generated by this practice can not be interpreted by any known models or theories. As clearinghouses hide counterparties, we can only see the clearinghouses in the data. The two contracts in each cleared swap pair have exactly the same counterparty (i.e., the same CCP) and terms and conditions but different swap rates. In other words, they appear to be identical in everything except swap rates. This violates the single value rule: two assets with identical information must be traded at the same price.

Since the clearinghouse is the counterparty in all transactions, counterparty credit risk is always the same for a dealer. Consequently, the prices of individual transactions should not be influenced by difference in counterparty credit risk, i.e., swap premium spreads should be zero in cleared markets. Said differently, the presence of swap premium spreads in cleared markets goes against the conventional wisdom and can not be explained theoretically and intuitively.

Second, there are many differences between cleared markets and OTC markets. The first difference is that cleared derivatives are over-collateralized as all CCPs require initial margins, whereas CSA derivatives in OTC markets are partially collateralized as all CSA counterparties maintain a positive MTA. The second difference is that cleared derivatives are subject to unilateral collateralization because only CCPs have the right to call for collateral, while OTC derivatives are most probably under bilateral collateralization. The third difference is that OTC collateral agreements always set a MTA to avoid the workload associated with a frequent transfer of insignificant amount of collateral between firms, whilst CCPs mark contracts to market daily and charge variation margins in response to changes in market values without a MTA.

The fourth difference is that variation margin in clearing markets is a linear function of daily market value changes. Whereas, collateral posted in OTC markets is a nonlinear function of daily market value changes. When the MTM value is greater than the threshold and the daily value change exceeds the MTA, collateral is called; otherwise, no transfer of collateral occurs. This non-linearity is the root cause of the complexity of pricing collateralized OTC derivatives.

The fifth difference is that a CCP mitigates credit risk via novation and multilateral netting. The novation process splits a contract into two – one setting out a sale and the other setting out the countervailing purchase – and substitutes the clearinghouse for the counterparty in each half of the transaction. Accordingly, the clearinghouse takes on credit risk on behalf of the original counterparties. The multilateral netting process enables offsets across market participants, which further ameliorates credit risk (see Cont and Kokholm (2011) and McPartland, et al. (2011)). In general, novation and multilateral netting processes change the risk structure that affects asset prices.

The last difference is that in cleared markets, a party receiving variation margin owns the funds and may withdraw them from the clearinghouse, while in OTC markets, a party posting collateral maintains ownership of the assets and receives interest (or coupons) on the assets. Many CCPs use the price alignment interest (PAI) adjustment or similar – a daily cash payment – to correct the difference in interest on variation margin between OTC contracts and CCP products (see Cont, Mondescu and Yu (2011)).

Even trivial variations between cleared and OTC markets can result in potentially large valuation discrepancy (see Pengelly (2011)). Given many differences between them, our theoretical study shows that over-collateralized derivatives in cleared markets are not economically equivalent to their partially collateralized counterparts in OTC markets.

Clearinghouses stand ready to act as counterparties to transactions with other market participants. The business of a clearinghouse closely resembles that of a specialized (monocline) insurer. Thus, the clearinghouse makes money in a similar way too – by charging fees to its members. For example, LCH Swap Clear does not levy a charge per transaction but instead charges its members an annual fee depending on their level of usage. Clearing members then pass on those charges to clients as part of their fee structure.

From a dealer’s perspective, market making involves costs and executing a transaction in a clearinghouse also entails expenses. Dealers that make markets must be compensated for incurring these costs and expanses. As a consequence, dealers in cleared markets also collect a swap premium for a transaction. However, swap premia charged in cleared markets should be different from those collected in OTC markets, as cost and risk structures have changed. At least, if two contracts have exactly the same terms and conditions as well as the same counterparty (i.e., the clearinghouse), they should have the same premia, as the swap premia should not be influenced by difference in counterparty credit risk in cleared markets. The discussions above may have important implications for regulators, academics and practitioners. A better understanding of collateralization would enable them to more accurately assess the impact of new regulation on financial markets.

  1. Conclusion

This article addresses a very important topic of the impact of collateralization on asset prices and risk management. This is the so called plumbing of financial system that affects many outcomes.

We present a comprehensive theoretical framework for pricing collateralized financial contracts based on the fundamental principal and legal structure of CSA agreements. The model can back out differences in asset prices due to collateralized counterparty risk. This is very useful for pricing outstanding defaultable financial contracts.

Empirically, we use a unique proprietary data set to measure the effect of collateralization on pricing and compare it with model-implied prices. We find a quite number of swap contracts that have different collateral arrangements but are similar otherwise. Presumably, differences in swap rates should be largely attributable to differences in counterparty risk. The empirical results show that model-implied prices are quite close to market-quoted prices, which suggests the model is fairly accurate in pricing collateralized contracts.

We find strong evidence that counterparty risk alone plays a significant but not overwhelming role in determining credit-related spreads for collateralized contracts. Only the joint effect of collateralization and credit risk can provide a sufficient explanation for unsecured credit costs. This finding suggests that failure to properly account for collateralization may result in significant mispricing of financial contracts.

We also find evidence that financial institutions are sprinting to comply with the Dodd-Frank Act. In the new practice, contracts are continuously negotiated over-the-counter as usual, but cleared and settled via clearinghouses, as clearinghouses claim that cleared contracts would be economically equivalent to their OTC counterparts. As a result, swap premia in cleared market are determined in a similar way to those in OTC markets. We argue that this practice may not be appropriate because we notice that the clearing mechanics of a clearinghouse change the risk structure and thereby the asset prices. In fact, we find that cleared derivatives are not economically equivalent to their OTC counterparts.

Appendix

or

where

Similarly, we have

Proof of Proposition 3: At time T, there are a total of four possible states shown in Table 1. The joint distributions of A and B are given by (18) and the collateral amount posted at time t is given by (19). Depending on whether the value is in the money or out of the money at T, we have the following situations

or

or

Combining the four cases together, we have

Where

References

AFME, ICMA, and ISDA, 2011, “The impact of derivative collateral policies of European sovereigns and resulting Basel III capital issues.”

Collin-Dufresne, P. and B. Solnik, 2001, “On the term structure of default premia in the swap and LIBOR markets,” Journal of Finance 56, 1095-1115.

Cont, R. and T. Kokholm, 2011, “Central clearing of OTC derivatives bilateral vs. multilateral netting,” Working paper.

Cont, R., R. Mondescu, and Y. Yu, 2011, “Central clearing of interest rate swaps: a comparison of offerings,” Working Paper.

Duffie, D. and M. Huang, 1996, “Swap rates and credit quality,” Journal of Finance, 51, 921-949.

Duffie, D., and K.J. Singleton, 1999, “Modeling term structure of defaultable bonds,” Review of Financial Studies, 12, 687-720.

Duffie, D., and H. Zhu, 2011, “Does a central clearing counterparty reduce counterparty risk?” Review of Asset Pricing Studies, 74-95.

Edwards, F. and E. Morrison, 2005, “Derivatives and the bankruptcy code: why the special treatment?” Yale Journal on Regulation, 22, 101-133.

Feldhutter, P. and D. Lando, 2008, “Decomposing swap spreads,” Journal of Financial Economics,” 88 (2), 375-405.

FinPricing, 2018, Swap Data, https://finpricing.com/lib/FiBond.html

European Central Bank (ECB), 2009, “Credit default swaps and counterparty risk.”

Fuijii, M. and A. Takahahsi, “Collateralized CDS and default dependence – Implications for the central clearing,” Forthcoming, Journal of Credit Risk.

Garlson, D., 1991-1992, “Secured creditors and the eely character of bankruptcy valuations,” 41 American University Law Review, 63, 63-106.

Grinblatt, M., 2001, “An analytic solution for interest rate swap spreads,” Review of International Finance, 2, 113-149.

https://github.com/timxiao1203/examine/raw/master/examining-collateralization-6.pdf

He, H., 2001, “Modeling Term Structures of Swap Spreads,” working paper, Yale School of Management, Yale University.

Heller, D. and N. Vause, 2012, “Collateral requirements for mandatory central clearing of over-the-counter derivatives,” BIS Working Papers, No 373.

Hentschel, L. and C. W. Smith, Jr., 1997, “Risks in Derivatives Markets: Implications for the Insurance Industry." Journal of Risk and Insurance, 64, 323-346.

Hull, J., 2010, “OTC derivatives and central clearing: can all transactions be cleared?” Financial Stability Review, 14, 71-80.

ISDA, 2013, Product Descriptions and Frequently Asked Questions (1. Major derivative categories; 2. How do cleared derivatives differ from OTC derivatives?), http://www.isda.org/educat/faqs.html

ISDA, 2012, “ISDA margin survey 2012.”

Johannes, M. and S. Sundaresan, 2007, “The impact of collateralization on swap rates,” Journal of Finance, 62, 383-410.

J.P. Morgan, 2001, “Par credit default swap spread approximation from default probabilities.”

Liu, J., F. Longstaff, and R. Mandell, 2006, "The Market Price of Risk in Interest Rate Swaps: The Roles of Default and Liquidity Risks," The Journal of Business, vol. 79, pages 2337-2360.

McPartland, J., P. Khorrami, R. Ranjan, and K. Wells, 2011, “An algorithm to estimate the total amount of collateral required before and after financial reform initiatives in various, regulatory jurisdictions,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.

Minton, B., 1997, “An Empirical Examination of Basic Valuation Models for Plain Vanilla U.S. Interest Rate Swaps." Journal of Financial Economics, 251-277.

Moody’s Investor’s Service, 2000, “Historical default rates of corporate bond issuers, 1920-99,”

O’Kane, D. and S. Turnbull, 2003, “Valuation of credit default swaps,” Fixed Income Quantitative Credit Research, Lehman Brothers, QCR Quarterly, 2003 Q1/Q2, 1-19.

Pengelly, M., 2011, “Margin minutiae at issue in Jefferies v IDCG suit,” Risk magazine, 02 Nov 2011

Pirrong, C., 2011, “The economics of central clearing: theory and practice,” ISDA Discussion Papers Series.

Piterbarg, V., 2010, “Funding beyond discounting: collateral agreements and derivatives pricing,” Risk Magazine, 2010 (2), 97-102.

Routh, R. and M. Douglas, 2005, “Default interest payable to oversecured creditor subject to reasonableness limitation,” ABF Journal, Vol. 4, No. 3.

Singh, M., 2010, “Collateral, netting and systemic risk in the OTC derivatives market,” IMF Working Paper No. 10/99.

Sorensen, E. and T. Bollier, 1994, “Pricing swap default risk,” Financial Analysts Journal, 50, 23-33.

Xiao, T., 2011, “An efficient lattice algorithm for the LIBOR market model,” Journal of Derivatives, 19 (1): 25-40.

Last updated