The Impact of Default Dependency and Collateralization on Asset Pricing and Credit Risk Modeling

The Impact of Default Dependency and Collateralization on Asset Pricing and Credit Risk Modeling

Tim Xiao

ABSTRACT

This article presents a comprehensive framework for valuing financial instruments subject to credit risk. In particular, we focus on the impact of default dependence on asset pricing, as correlated default risk is one of the most pervasive threats in financial markets. We analyze how swap rates are affected by bilateral counterparty credit risk, and how CDS spreads depend on the trilateral credit risk of the buyer, seller, and reference entity in a contract. Moreover, we study the effect of collateralization on valuation, since the majority of OTC derivatives are collateralized. The model shows that a fully collateralized swap is risk-free, whereas a fully collateralized CDS is not equivalent to a risk-free one.

Key Words: asset pricing; credit risk modeling; unilateral, bilateral, multilateral credit risk; collateralization; comvariance; comrelation; correlation.

  1. Introduction

A broad range of financial instruments bear credit risk. Credit risk may be unilateral, bilateral, or multilateral. Some instruments such as, loans, bonds, etc, by nature contain only unilateral credit risk because only the default risk of one party appears to be relevant, whereas some other instruments, such as, over the counter (OTC) derivatives, securities financing transactions (SFT), and credit derivatives, bear bilateral or multilateral credit risk because two or more parties are susceptible to default risk. This paper mainly discusses bilateral and multilateral credit risk modeling, with a particular focus on default dependency, as correlated credit risk is one of the greatest threats to global financial markets.

There are two primary types of models that attempt to describe default processes in the literature: structural models and reduced-form (or intensity) models. Many practitioners in the credit trading arena have tended to gravitate toward the reduced-from models given their mathematical tractability. They can be made consistent with the risk-neutral probabilities of default backed out from corporate bond prices or credit default swap (CDS) spreads/premia.

Central to the reduced-form models is the assumption that multiple defaults are independent conditional on the state of the economy. In reality, however, the default of one party might affect the default probabilities of other parties. Collin-Dufresne et al. (2003) and Zhang and Jorion (2007) find that a major credit event at one firm is associated with significant increases in the credit spreads of other firms. Giesecke (2004), Das et al. (2006), and Lando and Nielsen (2010) find that a defaulting firm can weaken the firms in its network of business links. These findings have important implications for the management of credit risk portfolios, where default relationships need to be explicitly modeled.

The main drawback of the conditionally independent assumption or the reduced-form models is that the range of default correlations that can be achieved is typically too low when compared with empirical default correlations (see Das et al. (2007)). The responses to correct this weakness can be generally classified into two categories: endogenous default relationship approaches and exogenous default relationship approaches.

The endogenous approaches include the contagion (or infectious) models and frailty models. The frailty models (see Duffie et al. (2009), Koopman et al. (2011), etc) describe default clustering based on some unobservable explanatory variables. In variations of contagion or infectious type models (see Davis and Lo (2001), Jarrow and Yu (2001), etc.), the assumption of conditional independence is relaxed and default intensities are made to depend on default events of other entities. Contagion and frailty models fill an important gap but at the cost of analytic tractability. They can be especially difficult to implement for large portfolios.

The exogenous approaches (see Li (2000), Laurent and Gregory (2005), Hull and White (2004), Brigo et al. (2011), etc) attempt to link marginal default probability distributions to the joint default probability distribution through some external functions. Due to their simplicity in use, the exogenous approaches become very popular in practice.

Collateralization is one of the most important and widespread credit risk mitigation techniques used in derivatives transactions. According the ISDA (2012), 71% of all OTC derivatives transactions are subject to collateral agreements. The use of collateral in the financial markets has increased sharply over the past decade, yet the research on collateralized valuation is relatively sparse. Previous studies seem to turn away from direct and detailed modeling of collateralization (see Fuijii and Takahahsi (2012)). For example, Johannes and Sundaresan (2007), and Fuijii and Takahahsi (2012) characterize collateralization via a cost-of-collateral instantaneous rate (or stochastic dividend or convenience yield). Piterbarg (2010) regards collateral as a regular asset in a portfolio and uses the replication approach to price collateralized contracts.

This paper presents a new framework for valuing defaultable financial instruments with or without collateral arrangements. The framework characterizes default dependencies exogenously, and models collateral processes directly based on the fundamental principals of collateral agreements. Some well-known risky valuation models in the markets, e.g., the CDS model, the risky interest rate swap (IRS) model (Duffie and Huang (1996)), can be viewed as special cases of this framework, when the default dependencies are ignored.

IRSs and CDSs are two of the largest segments of the OTC derivatives market, collectively accounting for around two-thirds of both the notional amount and market value of all outstanding derivatives. Given this framework, we are able to analyze the value of IRSs with bilateral credit risk and look at how swap rates are affected by correlated default risk. Our study shows that counterparty default correlations have a relatively small impact on swap rates. Furthermore, we find that the value of a fully collateralized IRS is equal to the risk-free value. This conclusion is consistent with the current market practice in which market participants commonly assume fully collateralized swaps are risk-free.

We also study the value of CDS contracts with trilateral credit risk and assess how spreads depend on the risk of the buyer, seller, and reference entity in a CDS contract. In general, a CDS contract is used to transfer the credit risk of a reference entity from one party to another. The risk circularity that transfers one type of risk (reference credit risk) into another (counterparty credit risk) within the CDS market is a concern for financial stability. Some people claim that the CDS market has increased financial contagion or even propose an outright ban on these instruments.

The standard CDS pricing model in the market assumes that there is no counterparty risk. Although this oversimplified model may be accepted in normal market conditions, its reliability in times of distress has recently been questioned. In fact, counterparty risk has become one of the most dangerous threats to the CDS market. For some time now it has been realized that, in order to value a CDS properly, counterparty effects have to be taken into account (see ECB (2009)).

We bring the concept of comvariance into the area of credit risk modeling to capture the statistical relationship among three or more random variables. Comvariance was first introduced to economics by Deardorff (1982), who used this measurement to correlate three factors in international trading. Furthermore, we define a new statistics, comrelation, as a scaled version of comvariance. Accounting for default correlations and comrelations becomes important in determining CDS premia, especially during the credit crisis. Our analysis shows that the effect of default dependencies on CDS premia from large to small is i) the default correlation between the protection seller and the reference entity, ii) the default comrelation, iii) the default correlation between the protection buyer and the reference entity, and iv) the default correlation between the protection buyer and the protection seller. In particular, we find that the default comvariance/comrelation has substantial effects on the asset pricing and risk management, which have never been documented.

There is a significant increase in the use of collateral for CDS after the recent financial crises. Many people believe that, if a CDS is fully collateralized, there is no risk of failure to pay. Collateral posting regimes are originally designed and utilized for bilateral risk products, e.g., IRS, but there are many reasons to be concerned about the success of collateral posting in offsetting the risk of CDS contracts. First, the value of CDS contracts tends to move very suddenly with big jumps, whereas the price movement of IRS contracts is far smoother and less volatile than CDS. Second, CDS spreads can widen very rapidly. Third, CDS contracts have many more risk factors than IRS contracts. In fact, our model shows that full collateralization cannot eliminate counterparty risk completely for a CDS.

This article also shows that the pricing process of a defaultable instrument normally has a backward recursive nature if the payoff can be positive or negative. Accordingly, we propose a backward induction approach for risky valuation. In contrast to the popular recursive integral solution (see Duffie and Huang (1996)), our backward induction method significantly simplifies the implementation. One can make use of the well-established algorithms, such as lattice/tree and regression-based Monte Carlo, to price a defaultable instrument.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows: Pricing bilateral defaultable instruments is elaborated on in Section 2; valuing multilateral defaultable instruments is discussed in Section 3; the conclusions are presented in Section 4. All proofs and some detailed derivations are contained in the appendices.

  1. Pricing Financial Instruments Subject to Bilateral Credit Risk

It is well-known that the survival probability from time t to s in this framework is defined by

The default probability for the period (t, s) in this framework is given by

Three different recovery models exist in the literature. The default payoff is either i) a fraction of par (Madan and Unal (1998)), ii) a fraction of an equivalent default-free bond (Jarrow and Turnbull (1995)), or iii) a fraction of market value (Duffie and Singleton (1999)). The whole course of the recovery proceedings under the Bankruptcy and Insolvency act is a complex process that typically involves extensive negotiation and litigation. No model can fully capture all aspects of this process so, in practice, all models involve trade-offs between different perspectives and views. In general, the choice for a certain recovery assumption is based on the legal structure of an instrument to be priced. For example, the recovery of market value (RMV) assumption is well matched to the legal structure of an IRS contract where, upon default close-out, valuation will in many circumstances reflect the replacement cost of the transaction, whereas the best default recovery assumption for a CDS is that the claim made in the event of the reference default equals a fraction of the face value of the underlying bond.

There is ample evidence that corporate defaults are correlated. The default of a firm’s counterparty might affect its own default probability. Thus, default correlation/dependence arises due to the counterparty relations.

A critical ingredient of the pricing of a bilateral defaultable instrument is the default settlement rules. There are two rules in the market. The one-way payment rule was specified by the early International Swap Dealers Association (ISDA) master agreement. The non-defaulting party is not obligated to compensate the defaulting party if the remaining market value of the instrument is positive for the defaulting party. The two-way payment rule is based on current ISDA documentation. The non-defaulting party will pay the full market value of the instrument to the defaulting party if the contract has positive value to the defaulting party.

1.1 Risky valuation without collateralization

The risky value of the instrument at time t is the discounted expectation of all the payoffs and is given by

where

where

Equation (9) is the same as equation (2.5’) in Duffie and Huang (1996).

In theory, a default may happen at any time, i.e., a risky contract is continuously defaultable. This Continuous Time Risky Valuation Model is accurate but sometimes complex and expensive. For simplicity, people sometimes prefer the Discrete Time Risky Valuation Model that assumes that a default may only happen at some discrete times. A natural selection is to assume that a default may occur only on the payment dates. Fortunately, the level of accuracy for this discrete approximation is well inside the typical bid-ask spread for most applications (see O’Kane and Turnbull (2003)). From now on, we will focus on the discrete setting only, but many of the points we make are equally applicable to the continuous setting.

If we assume that a default may occur only on the payment date, the risky value of the instrument in a discrete-time setting is given by

where

Proposition 1: The risky value of the multiple-payment instrument is given by

Proof: See the Appendix.

1.2 Risky valuation with collateralization

Collateralization is the most important and widely used technique in practice to mitigate credit risk. The posting of collateral is regulated by the Credit Support Annex (CSA) that specifies a variety of terms including the threshold, the independent amount, and the minimum transfer amount (MTA), etc. The threshold is the unsecured credit exposure that a party is willing to bear. The minimum transfer amount is the smallest amount of collateral that can be transferred. The independent amount plays the same role as the initial margin (or haircuts).

In a typical collateral procedure, a financial instrument is periodically marked-to-market and the collateral is adjusted to reflect changes in value. The collateral is called as soon as the mark-to-market (MTM) value rises above the given collateral threshold, or more precisely, above the threshold amount plus the minimum transfer amount. Thus, the collateral amount posted at time t is given by

The main role of collateral should be viewed as an improved recovery in the event of a counterparty default. According to Bankruptcy law, if there has been no default, the collateral is returned to the collateral giver by the collateral taker. If a default occurs, the collateral taker possesses the collateral. In other words, collateral does not affect the survival payment; instead, it takes effect on the default payment only.

or

If we assume that default probabilities are uncorrelated with interest rates and payoffs[2], we have

Equation (14) is the formula for the risk-free valuation. Thus, we have the following proposition.

Proposition 2: If a bilateral risky instrument is fully collateralized, the risky value of the instrument is equal to the risk-free value, as shown in equation (14).

Since an IRS is a typical bilateral risky contract, Proposition 2 squares with the results of Johannes and Sundaresan (2007), and is also consistent with the current market practice in which market participants commonly assume fully collateralized swaps are risk-free and it is common to build models of swap rates assuming that swaps are free of counterparty risk.

1.3 Numerical results

To study the impact of bilateral credit risk, we have selected a new 10-year fixed-for-floating IRS with a quarterly payment frequency. Two counterparties are denoted as A and B. Counterparty A pays a fixed rate and counterparty B pays a floating rate. All calculations are from the perspective of party A.

The current (spot) market data are shown in Table 2, provided by FinPricing (2019). At the time the contract is entered into, there is no advantage to either party. By definition, a swap rate is a fixed rate that makes the market value of a given swap at initiation zero. The risk-free swap rate can be easily calculated as 0.03433.

Since the payoff of an IRS is determined by interest rates, we need to model the evolution of the floating rates. Interest rate models are based on evolving either short rates, instantaneous forward rates, or market forward rates (e.g., the LIBOR Market Model (LMM)). Since both short rates and instantaneous forward rates are not directly observable in the market, the models based on these rates have difficulties in expressing market views and quotes in term of model parameters, and lack agreement with market valuation formulas for basic derivatives. On the other hand, the object modeled under the LMM is market-observable. It is also consistent with the market standard approach for pricing caps/floors using Black’s formula. They are generally considered to have more desirable theoretical calibration properties than short rate or instantaneous forward rate models. Therefore, we choose the LMM lattice proposed by Xiao (2011) for pricing the defaultable IRS. We also implement the Hull-White trinomial tree to verify the results and ensure robustness of the valuation. This paper, however, only reports the results produced by the LMM lattice.

We first assume that i) counterparties A and B have independent default risks; ii) the hazard rates are deterministic; and iii) both parties have a constant recovery of 60%. We use the LMM to evolve the interest rates and then price the risky IRS according to Proposition 1. The risky swap rates are computed and shown in Table 3.

From Table 3, we derive the following conclusions: First, a fixed-rate payer with lower credit quality (higher credit risk) pays a higher fixed rate. Second, a credit spread of about 100 basis points translates into a swap spread of about 1.3 basis points. Finally, the credit impact on swap rates is approximately linear within the range of normally encountered credit quality. This confirms the findings of Duffie and Huang (1996). Intuitively, a risk-free floating-rate payer demands a higher fixed rate if the fixed-rate payer has a lower credit score.

We next present some new results. Assume that party A has an ‘A+300bps’ credit quality, i.e., a ‘300 basis points’ parallel shift in the A-rated credit spreads, and party B has an ‘A’ credit quality. The risky swap rate with asymmetric credit qualities is calculated as 0.03436.

Bilateral credit risk modeling is probably the simplest example involving default dependency, but it shows several essential features for modeling correlated credit risk, which will help the reader better understand the increasingly complex cases in the following section.

2 Pricing Financial Instruments Subject to Multilateral Credit Risk

The interest in the financial industry for the modeling and pricing of multilateral defaultable instruments arises mainly in two respects: in the management of credit risk at a portfolio level and in the valuation of credit derivatives. Central to the pricing and risk management of credit derivatives and credit risk portfolios is the issue of default relationships.

Let us discuss the three-party case first. A CDS is a good example of a trilateral defaultable instrument where the three parties are counterparties A, B and reference entity C. In a standard CDS contract one party purchases credit protection from another party, to cover the loss of the face value of a reference entity following a credit event. The protection buyer makes periodic payments to the seller until the maturity date or until a credit event occurs. A credit event usually requires a final accrual payment by the buyer and a loss protection payment by the protection seller. The protection payment is equal to the difference between par and the price of the cheapest to deliver (CTD) asset of the reference entity on the face value of the protection.

A CDS is normally used to transfer the credit risk of a reference entity between two counterparties. The contract reduces the credit risk of the reference entity but gives rise to another form of risk: counterparty risk. Since the dealers are highly concentrated within a small group, any of them may be too big to fail. The interconnected nature, with dealers being tied to each other through chains of OTC derivatives, results in increased contagion risk. Due to its concentration and interconnectedness, the CDS market seems to pose a systemic risk to financial market stability. In fact, the CDS is blamed for playing a pivotal role in the collapse of Lehman Brothers and the disintegration of AIG.

For years, a widespread practice in the market has been to mark CDS to market without taking the counterparty risk into account. The realization that even the most prestigious investment banks could go bankrupt has shattered the foundation of the practice. It is wiser to face frankly the real complexities of pricing a CDS than to indulge in simplifications that have proved treacherous. For some time now it has been realized that, in order to value a CDS properly, counterparty effects have to be taken into account.

where

We introduce the concept of comvariance into credit risk modeling arena to exploit any statistical relationship among multiple random variables. Furthermore, we define a new statistic, comrelation, as a scaled version of comvariance (just like correlation is a scaled version of covariance) as follows:

According to the Holder inequality, we have

Obviously, the comrelation is in the range of [-1, 1]. Given the comrelation, Equation (15i) can be rewritten as

More generally, we define the comrelation in the context of n random variables as

2.1 Risky valuation without collateralization

Recovery assumptions are important for pricing credit derivatives. If the reference entity under a CDS contract defaults, the best assumption, as pointed out by J. P. Morgan (1999), is that the recovered value equals the recovery rate times the face value plus accrued interest[3]. In other words, the recovery of par value assumption is a better fit upon the default of the reference entity, whereas the recovery of market value assumption is a more suitable choice in the event of a counterparty default.

Proposition 3: The value of the multiple-payment CDS is given by

Proof: See the Appendix.

Corollary 1: If counterparties A and B are default-free, the value of the multiple-payment CDS is given by

2.2 Risky valuation with collateralization

According to the ISDA (2012), almost all CDSs are fully collateralized. Many people believe that full collateralization can eliminate counterparty risk completely for CDS.

Collateral posting regimes are originally designed and utilized for bilateral risk products, e.g., IRS, but there are many reasons to be concerned about the success of collateral posting in offsetting the risks of CDS contracts. First, the values of CDS contracts tend to move very suddenly with big jumps, whereas the price movements of IRS contracts are far smoother and less volatile than CDS prices. Second, CDS spreads can widen very rapidly. The amount of collateral that one party is required to provide at short notice may, in some cases, be close to the notional amount of the CDS and may therefore exceed that party’s short-term liquidity capacity, thereby triggering a liquidity crisis. Third, CDS contracts have many more risk factors than IRS contracts.

or

where

Proposition 4: If a CDS is fully collateralized, the risky value of the CDS is NOT equal to the counterparty-risk-free value, as shown in equation (26).

2.3 Numerical results

Our goal in this subsection is to study the quantitative relationship between the CDS premium and the credit qualities of the counterparties and reference entity, including the default correlations and comrelation in a CDS contract.

In our study, we choose a new 5-year CDS with a quarterly payment frequency. Two counterparties are denoted as A and B. Counterparty A buys a protection from counterparty B. All calculations are from the perspective of party A. By definition, a breakeven CDS spread is a premium that makes the market value of a given CDS at inception zero. Assume that the reference entity C has an “A+200bps” credit quality throughout this subsection. The 5-year counterparty-risk-free CDS premium is 0.027 (equals the 5-year ‘A’ rated CDS spread in Table 2 plus 200 basis points).

Since the payoffs of a CDS are mainly determined by credit events, we need to characterize the evolution of the hazard rates. Here we choose the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR) model. The CIR process has been widely used in the literature of credit risk and is given by

The calibrated parameters are shown in table 4. We assume that interest rates are deterministic and select the regression-based Monte-Carlo simulation (see Longstaff and Schwartz (2001)) to perform risky valuation.

From table 5 and 6, we find that a credit spread of about 100 basis points maps into a CDS premium of about 0.4 basis points for counterparty A and about -0.7 basis points for counterparty B. The credit impact on the CDS premia is approximately linear. As would be expected, i) the dealer’s credit quality has a larger impact on CDS premia than the investor’s credit quality; ii) the higher the investor’s credit risk, the higher the premium that the dealer charges; iii) the higher the dealer’s credit risk, the lower the premium that the dealer asks. Without considering default correlations and comrelations, we find that, in general, the impact of counterparty risk on CDS premia is relatively small. This is in line with the empirical findings of Arora, Gandhi, and Longstaff (2009).

3 Conclusion

This article presents a new valuation framework for pricing financial instruments subject to credit risk. In particular, we focus on modeling default relationships. Some well-known risky valuation models in the market can be viewed as special cases of this framework, when the default dependencies are ignored.

To capture the default relationships among more than two defaultable entities, we introduce a new statistic: comrelation, an analogue to correlation for multiple variables, to exploit any multivariate statistical relationship. Our research shows that accounting for default correlations and comrelations becomes important, especially under market stress. The existing valuation models in the credit derivatives market, which take into account only pair-wise default correlations, may underestimate credit risk and may be inappropriate.

We study the sensitivity of the price of a defaultable instrument to changes in the joint credit quality of the parties. For instance, our analysis shows that the effect of default dependence on CDS premia from large to small is the correlation between the protection seller and the reference entity, the comrelation, the correlation between the protection buyer and the reference entity, and the correlation between the protection buyer and the protection seller.

The model shows that a fully collateralized swap is risk-free, while a fully collateralized CDS is not equivalent to a risk-free one. Therefore, we conclude that collateralization designed to mitigate counterparty risk works well for financial instruments subject to bilateral credit risk, but fails for ones subject to multilateral credit risk.

Appendix

Similarly, we have

where

Similarly, we have

References

Arora, Navneet, Priyank Gandhi, and Francis A. Longstaff (2009), “Counterparty credit risk and the credit default swap market,” Working paper, UCLA.

Brigo, D., A. Pallavicini, and R. Torresetti (2011), “Credit Models and the Crisis: default cluster dynamics and the Generalized Poisson Loss model,” Journal of Credit Risk, 6: 39-81.

Collin-Dufresne, P., R. Goldstein, and J. Helwege (2003), “Is credit event risk priced? Modeling contagion via the updating of beliefs,” Working paper, Haas School, University of California, Berkeley.

Das, S., D. Duffie, N. Kapadia, and L. Saita (2007), “Common failings: How corporate defaults are correlated,” Journal of Finance, 62: 93-117.

Das, S., L. Freed, G. Geng, N. Kapadia (2006), “Correlated default risk,” Journal of Fixed Income, 16: 7-32.

Davis, M., and V. Lo (2001), “Infectious defaults,” Quantitative Finance, 1: 382-387.

Deardorff, Alan V. (1982): “The general validity of the Heckscher-Ohlin Theorem,” American Economic Review, 72 (4): 683-694.

Duffie, D., A. Eckner, G. Horel, and L. Saita (2009), “Frailty correlated default,” Journal of Finance, 64: 2089-2123.

Duffie, D., and M. Huang (1996), “Swap rates and credit quality,” Journal of Finance, 51: 921-949.

Duffie, D., and K. Singleton (1999), “Modeling term structure of defaultable bonds,” Review of Financial Studies, 12: 687-720.

ECB (2009), “Credit default swaps and counterparty risk,” European central bank.

FinPricing, 2019, Market data services, https://finpricing.com/lib/FxVolIntroduction.html

Fuijii, M. and A. Takahahsi (2012), “Collateralized CDS and default dependence – Implications for the central clearing,” Journal of Credit Risk, 8(3): 97-113.

Giesecke, K. (2004), “Correlated default with incomplete information,” Journal of Banking and Finance, 28: 1521-1545.

https://github.com/timxiao1203/dependency/raw/master/default-dependency-collateralization-7.pdf

Hull, J. and A. White (2004), “Valuation of a CDO and a nth to default CDS without Monte Carlo simulation,” Journal of Derivatives, 12: 8-23.

ISDA (2012), “ISDA margin survey 2012.”

Jarrow, R., and S. Turnbull (1995), “Pricing derivatives on financial securities subject to credit risk,” Journal of Finance, 50: 53-85.

Jarrow, R., and F. Yu (2001), “Counterparty risk and the pricing of defaultable securities,” Journal of Finance, 56: 1765-99.

Johannes, M. and S. Sundaresan (2007), “The impact of collateralization on swap rates,” Journal of Finance, 62: 383-410.

J. P. Morgan (1999), “The J. P. Morgan guide to credit derivatives,” Risk Publications.

Koopman, S., A. Lucas, and B. Schwaab (2011), “Modeling frailty-correlated defaults using many macroeconomic covariates,” Journal of Econometrics, 162: 312-325.

Lando, D. and M. Nielsen (2010), “Correlation in corporate defaults: contagion or conditional independence?” Journal of Financial Intermediation, 19: 355-372.

Laurent, J. and J. Gregory (2005), “Basket default swaps, CDOs and factor copulas,” Journal of Risk, 7:

03-122.

Li, D. (2000), “On default correlation: A copula function approach,” Journal of Fixed Income, 9: 43-54.

Longstaff, F., and E. Schwartz (2001): “Valuing American options by simulation: a simple least-squares approach,” The Review of Financial Studies, 14 (1): 113-147.

Madan, D., and H. Unal (1998), “Pricing the risks of default,” Review of Derivatives Research, 2: 121-160.

Moody’s Investor’s Service (2000): “Historical default rates of corporate bond issuers, 1920-99,”

O’Kane, D. and S. Turnbull (2003), “Valuation of credit default swaps,” Fixed Income Quantitative Credit Research, Lehman Brothers, QCR Quarterly, Q1/Q2: 1-19.

Piterbarg, V. (2010), “Funding beyond discounting: collateral agreements and derivatives pricing,” Risk Magazine, 2010 (2): 97-102.

Teugels, J. (1990), “Some representations of the multivariate Bernoulli and binomial distributions,” Journal of Multivariate Analysis, 32: 256-268.

Xiao, T. (2011), “An efficient lattice algorithm for the LIBOR market model,” Journal of Derivatives, 19 (1): 25-40.

Zhang, G., and P. Jorion, (2007), “Good and bad credit contagion: Evidence from credit default swaps,” Journal of Financial Economics 84: 860–883.

Table 1. Payoffs of a bilateral risky instrument

Table 2: Current/spot market data

This table displays the current (spot) market data used for all calculations in this paper, including the term structure of continuously compounded interest rates, the term structure of A-rated breakeven CDS spreads, and the curve of at-the-money caplet volatilities.

Table 3. Impact of the credit quality of the fixed-rate payer on swap rates

Table 4: Risk-neutral parameters for CIR model

This table presents the risk-neutral parameters that are calibrated to the current market shown in Table 2. ‘A+100bps’ represents a ‘100 basis points’ parallel shift in the A-rated CDS spreads.

Table 5: Impact of the credit quality of the protection buyer on CDS premia

This table shows how the CDS premium increases as the credit quality of party A decreases. The 1st data column represents the counterparty-risk-free results. For the remaining columns, we assume that party B is risk-free and party A is risky. ‘A+100bps’ represents a ‘100 basis points’ parallel shift in the A-rated CDS spreads. The results in the row ‘Difference from Risk-Free’ = current CDS premium – counterparty-risk-free CDS premium.

Table 6: Impact of the credit quality of the protection seller on CDS premia

This table shows the decrease in the CDS premium with the credit quality of party B. The 1st data column represents the counterparty-risk-free results. For the remaining columns, we assume that party A is risk-free and party B is risky. ‘A+100bps’ represents a ‘100 basis points’ parallel shift in the A-rated CDS spreads. The results in the row ‘Difference from Risk-Free’ = current CDS premium – counterparty-risk-free CDS premium.

Table A1. Payoffs of a trilateral risky CDS

Figure 1. Impact of default correlation on swap rates

The curve in this diagram represents the sensitivity of swap rates to changes in counterparty default correlation. Party A has an ‘A+300bps’ credit quality and party B has an ‘A’ credit quality. ‘A+300bps’ represents a ‘300 basis points’ parallel shift in the A-rated CDS spreads.

Figure 2: Impact of default correlations and comrelation on CDS premia

Last updated